Front page
'
Arts
'
Economics
'
Food and drink
'
Travel |
![]() |
Natural environment and climate change
The value in environmental valuation An article by Mallika Ishwaran, Jonathan Portes and Richard Price .
|
Mallika Ishwaran, Jonathan Portes and Richard Price 1, August 2011
The UK has been at the forefront in using new techniques to shape policy
decisions which affect the environment. As former and existing advisers
in government, we have all felt the pressure from inside and outside
government to make sure decisions are based on the best possible science
and economics. That includes understanding how changes in the
environment affect people’s lives – both today, and for future
generations.
The latest development pioneered by the UK is the remarkable National
Ecosystem Assessment (NEA)2.
We think it is a unique and powerful study which assesses the state of
the UK’s natural capital; shows how it has changed over the past few
decades, and helps to assess how different policy choices might shape it
for the future. Others have a different view. George Monbiot
described it as
First, the principled objection, that it is impossible to put a value on
the services and satisfaction we derive from nature. This ignores the
fact that decisions are made daily which affect the environment and
which require trade-offs to be made between different objectives. It is
critical that we provide the best assessment of environmental impacts of
alternatives, alongside the value of other kinds of benefits such as
employment, economic growth and reliable infrastructure. In fact,
our work suggests that looking after the environment can also help to
support these objectives – so it is not always ‘either/or’, But in many
cases trade-offs need to be made, either implicitly or explicitly,
to allocate limited resources towards achieving these various
objectives. “To govern is to choose”, and valuation has proved a helpful
way of making choices better informed and transparent.
For example, in deciding whether to provide planning consent a local
authority has to make a judgement about the overall value to the
community from a development, balancing factors such as additional jobs
and income with the value to the community from keeping the green space.
As economists, we could wash our hands and say it was impossible to
assess that value; but the local authority still has to say yes or no to
the planning consent. And either way, it is implicitly
making a judgement about how large that value really is.
More generally, many of the benefits we derive from the natural
environment don't have market prices, so they are not reflected in
standard measures of economic activity. Environmental valuation puts
environmental objectives on a more equal footing in policy decisions
with things which do have a price. That doesn't mean that
valuations always capture everything there is to know about the benefits
we get from nature. But together with other considerations, they
allow us to make the comparisons and tradeoffs that are a critical
element of informed and balanced decision-making.
The second objection is more practical; the
perception that placing an explicit value on nature is a precursor for
anti-environment policies. Monbiot again:
This is just not true. In fact, Defra's guidance
on how to assess the value of ecosystem services in cost-benefit
analysis of policies requires departments systematically to factor in
environmental impacts and risks in a way which markets generally don't.4
It gives a systematic and consistent way of taking account of
environmental impacts in policy development and appraisal – not just in
the context of environmental policies but in all government policies
which affect the natural world. Its value lies as much in helping
to assess and mitigate potential environmental harm in policy decisions
as in supporting policies which enhance the state of the environment.
Far from rigging the process in favour of business, it ensures that
cost-benefit analysis goes beyond financial costs and benefits to
reflect non-market environmental impacts.
It's worth looking at a few examples of how this sort of cost-benefit
analysis is applied in practice, both inside and outside government; not
just in making environmental choices but in other policy areas too:
·
the number of cataract surgeries performed has risen nearly four-fold
over the last two decades, to about 300,000 a year. At a cost of
several thousand pounds, is this expansion justified given other
pressures on the NHS? Research by Martin Weale at the National
Institute of Economic and Social Research found that for almost (but not
quite) all patients, the value to them from the improved quality of life
resulting from better eyesight was well in excess of the cost;
·
Costs and benefits are used to assess impacts on environmental value in
the design of infrastructure. For example the Department for Transport’s
approach on road location and design systematically gives weight to
environmental amenity, pollution and noise to identify the best options
for addressing them. Looking at options in this way makes a real
difference to the way projects are configured – for example the
recently-opened A3 Hindhead Improvement project was carefully designed
to achieve a reduction in noise pollution and harm to the landscape.
And beyond local impacts, transport policy plays a big part in tackling
carbon emissions and air quality, and valuation of environmental impacts
is at the heart of decision-making.
·
the move away from old-style farm subsidies towards agri-environmental
schemes and a ‘payment for ecosystem services’ approach is justified on
the basis of the social value of uplands landscapes. For example, in
2010 a new scheme was launched to pay hill farmers to support better
environmental management. Valuation studies for Defra identified the
potential to get much bigger benefits from agri-environmental schemes
compared to equivalent subsidies with weak or no links to environmental
outcomes. Crucially, it also helped establish that agri-environmental
schemes were more socially valuable than simply stopping farm payments,
which would have led to land abandonment in the uplands, with
significant environmental damage.
Of course cost-benefit analysis isn't the answer to everything. No
sensible economist would pretend otherwise. But it is a valuable
tool - and it is absurd for either economists or commentators to bury
their heads in the sand and pretend that government doesn't need it to
make these sorts of decisions in an informed way. The publication
of the NEA puts the underlying data and assumptions out in the public
domain, to be criticised, debated and improved. That is good for
transparency, good for policymaking, and good for the environment.
Footnotes and references 1 Mallika Ishwaran is Acting Chief Economist, Defra; Jonathan Portes is Director, National Institute of Social and Economic Research; Richard Price is Chief Executive, Office of Rail Regulation and author of the Government Economic Service’s reviews of sustainable development and social impacts 2 The UK National Ecosystems Assessment can be found here: http://uknea.unep-wcmc.org/ 3 George Monbiot: "The true value of nature is not a number with a pound sign in front" The Guardian, 6 June 2011.
4
This is published as a supplement to the Treasury’s
Green Book,which
sets out the framework for assessing policies, programmes and projects
across central government. Link to the original article at the National Ecosystem Assessment: The value in environmental valuation |
||